HAL Id: hal-00972851
https://sciencespo.hal.science/hal-00972851
Submitted on 21 May 2014
HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access
archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci-
entic research documents, whether they are pub-
lished or not. The documents may come from
teaching and research institutions in France or
abroad, or from public or private research centers.
L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est
destinée au dépôt et à la diusion de documents
scientiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non,
émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de
recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires
publics ou privés.
Who Captures Whom? Trade Policy Lobbying in the
European Union
Cornelia Woll
To cite this version:
Cornelia Woll. Who Captures Whom? Trade Policy Lobbying in the European Union. Coen David,
Richardson Jeremy. Lobbying in the European Union: Institutions, Actors and Issues, Oxford Uni-
versity Press, pp.268-288, 2009, 9780199207350. �hal-00972851�
Trade Policy Lobbying in the European Union: Who Captures Whom?
Cornelia Woll
Pre-Print
Published in David Coen and Jeremy Richardson (eds.), Lobbying in the European
Union: Institutions, Actors and Issues, (Oxford University Press, 2009), p. 268-288.
This version: October 2008
2
Introduction
Trade policy is a classic field for the study of private influence on policy-making.
Firms and industries can gain clear advantages by protecting their markets from
foreign competition or by gaining access to other countries. A large portion of the
literature on international political economy therefore explains policy choices with
reference to the demands of constituent interests (see Frieden and Martin 2002). For
anybody interested in business lobbying, trade policy would seem to be the most
appropriate place to start.
And yet, comparing trade policy lobbying in the U.S. and the EU leaves many
observers surprised. Aggressive business lobbying on trade issues is much less
common in Brussels than it is in Washington, D.C. (e.g. Coen 1999; cf. Woll 2006).
Shaffer (2003: 6) underlines that U.S. firms and trade associations are very proactive
in business–government relations on trade policy. This “bottom-up” approach
contrasts with the “top down” EU approach where public authority, in particular the
European Commission, plays the predominant entrepreneurial role.
While the U.S. Trade Representative responded to onslaughts of private
sector lobbying reinforced by congressional phone calls and committee
grillings, the Commission had to contact firms to contact it (Shaffer
2003: 70).
Indeed, the European Commission has made a concerted effort to integrate
firms and other private actors into the trade policy-making process in order to gain
bargaining leverage not simply vis-à-vis third countries, but also over its own member
states (Van den Hoven 2002; Elsig 2007). By helping to elaborate policy solutions,
3
interest group participation increases the legitimacy of the Commission on external
trade issues.
This reverse lobbying is not without consequences. While firms do
increasingly seize the opportunities available to them at the supranational level, EU
trade policy lobbying is marked by a particular logic. Firms face a trade-off between
pressing for immediate advantages and responding to the interests of the European
Commission, which promises them access to the policy-making process (Broscheid
and Coen 2003). Since the Commission is not immediately accountable to
constituency interests, it can select interest groups and firms that it prefers to work
with and ignore others (Grande 1996). In selecting private partners, the Commission
follows two objectives. First, it requires technical expertise to develop its policy
proposals (Bouwen 2002). Second, and on trade issues in particular, it is interested in
finding pan-European solutions to prevent disputes between the member states that
would risk stalling trade negotiations (Shaffer 2003: 78-79). When protectionist
measures depend on national boundaries, industry privileges are likely to conflict with
the Commission’s goals. Firms therefore have to decide between lobbying for their
immediate advantage at the risk of being ignored, and framing their demands in terms
of a pan-European interest even if they are not certain of obtaining an advantage.
This logic creates two distinct channels for trade policy lobbying in the EU. A
firm or industry interested in classic protectionism is most successful when it uses a
national lobbying strategy directed at the member states and ultimately the Council of
Ministers. Supranational lobbying, in turn, requires framing demands to include a
pan-European dimensions. Lobbyists thus have to find ways of proposing pan-
European protectionism, most commonly in the form of pan-European trade
4
regulation (Young 2004). Alternatively, they can lobby for trade liberalization in
order to establish or maintain contacts with the European Commission and then hope
to integrate more precise demands in the details of trade regulation or the
implementation of agreements.
By studying the Europeanization of trade policy and the instruments firms
employ to affect EU trade policy, a first part of this paper underlines the complexity
individual firms have to manage in order to influence the Community stance on
international trade negotiations. As an illustration of the EU trade policy lobbying
logic, a second part then turns to concrete policy examples and compares the
protectionist lobbying on agriculture and textiles and clothing with the lobbying on
service trade liberalization in financial services and telecommunications. The
conclusion discusses the extent to which the findings on business lobbying have
implications for other actors seeking to affect trade policy, most notably NGOs or
public interest groups.
1. Trade policy lobbying in the multi-level system
Trade policy is one of the most integrated policy areas in the EU, and yet the
struggle over the competence distribution between the supranational institutions and
the member states is crucial for understanding lobbying in this domain. Before turning
to the key instruments for corporate lobbying on EU trade, it is therefore necessary to
understand the Europeanization of trade policy and the history of competence
delegation from the member states to the EU Institutions.
5
1.1. The integration of trade policy-making
The common commercial policy is as old as the European Economic
Community itself. With the Treaty of Rome in 1957, member states agreed that a
customs union requires a common external tariff, common trade agreements with
third countries and uniform application across member states (Elsig 2002; Meunier
2005). They granted the European institutions the right to speak on their behalf on
these issues in external trade negotiations.
1
Initially, this authority applied to tariff
rates, anti-dumping and subsidies, which were indeed the main stakes in early
multilateral trade negotiations under the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
(GATT). During the Tokyo Round of GATT (1973-9) and especially during the
Uruguay Round (1986-94), non-tariff barriers to trade started to gain importance,
including health, environmental and social aspects of trade policy, and the domestic
regulatory issues applying to the trade in services. European trade authority did not
apply to many of these issues, which pushed the Community to redefine trade
competences and the degree of delegation from the member states to the EU. In
particular, it stirred up a debate over which issues should fall under “exclusive” or
“mixed” competence (Meunier and Nicolaïdis 1999; Meunier 2000a).
Mixed competence means that trade authority is delegated on an ad hoc basis
to the Community. The setting of objectives and the ratification of the negotiation
results are subject to a unanimous vote by the Council, whereas both require only a
1
Articles 131-135 (ex 110-116) of the Treaty on European Union. Article 300 (ex
228) provides the supranational institutions with powers to conclude trade agreements
with third countries.
6
qualified majority under exclusive competence. Over time, many areas of mixed
competence have been dealt with pragmatically at first, by letting the Commission
negotiate without fully resolving the competence dispute. For the results to be
adopted, however, the legal competence question has become pressing. When the
European Court of Justice decided effectively against an automatic expansion of trade
competences in 1994, the Commission and the member states first agreed on a code of
conduct and later adopted a special competence transfer procedure in 1996 (Elsig
2002: 90-101; Meunier 2000b: 338-40). It was not until 2003 that the Treaty of Nice
finally amended Article 133 and provided for the exclusive competence over services
and intellectual property rights, with the exception of cultural and audio-visual
services. The struggle underlines how heavily disputed the transfer of authority is.
Delegation is a delicate matter, even in this highly integrated policy domain, and
control mechanisms employed by member states are tight (De Bièvre and Dür 2005).
The various control mechanisms become evident when one considers the
different stages in the trade policy-making cycle. Woolcock (2000) distinguishes
between (1) the setting of objectives, (2) the conduct of negotiations and (3) the
adoption of results.
The negotiation objectives are decided by the General Affairs
Council of foreign ministers on the basis of a Commission proposal. Long before the
formal adoption of a mandate, the Commission submits the proposal to the member
states or, more precisely, to the national trade officials representing their governments
on the Article 133 Committee (see Johnson 1998). Discussions during this phase are
crucial, since the Commission can use the Article 133 Committee “as a sounding
board to ensure that it is on the right track” (Shaffer 2003: 79). Trying to achieve a
consensus on the mandate, the Article 133 Committee examines and amends the
7
proposal before handing it to the Committee of Permanent Representatives
(COREPER) and eventually the Council. Neither the European Parliament nor the
general public participate formally in these early negotiations, which take place
behind closed doors in order to shield the negotiation objectives from the trading
partners. Woolcock (2000: 380) underlines how sharply the role of the European
Parliament contrasts with the role of the U.S. Congress. Indeed, constituents lobbying
their representatives have more direct control over the negotiating mandate in the
U.S., where Congress can grant or withhold negotiation authority.
The conduct of negotiations is the responsibility of the Commission, but even
in areas of exclusive competence, consultation with the member states is crucial. The
Article 133 Committee closely follows negotiations and the EU negotiation team
meets daily with member state representatives. On sensitive issues such as service
trade liberalization, trading partners have jokingly remarked that the Commission
negotiates more with the member states than with the rest of the world (Woll 2004:
227). The Commission, furthermore, tries to keep the External Economic Relations
Committee of the European Parliament informed, even though the Parliament has no
speaking rights during negotiations. Results are adopted by the General Affairs
Council either by qualified majority voting under exclusive competence or by
unanimous decision under mixed competence. In practice, however, consensus
decisions are the norm (Woolcock 2000: 384).
The importance of consensus between the member states applies equally to
dispute settlement procedures. The most common way to bring a dispute to the WTO
is for the Commission to initiate a case after consultation with the Article 133
Committee. Formal procedure requires conflictual issues to be transferred to
8
COREPER and subsequently to the Council, should all other instances fail to resolve
the dispute. In all the time the WTO has employed the dispute settlement procedure,
this has only happened once.
2
According to Shaffer (2003: 80) “neither committee
members nor the Commission wish to transfer decision-making authority on trade
matters from themselves, who are trade experts, to the Council, which consists of
foreign affairs ministers.”
To summarize, all stages of trade policy-making are characterized by an
explicit desire to achieve and maintain consensus between the member states. The
Commission cannot negotiate effectively if the EU member states are not behind the
Community objectives. The interlocking of member state control and Commission
authority are thus the two important dimensions of trade policy-making that interest
groups and firms need to take into account if they wish to lobby effectively.
1.2. Instruments and venues for corporate lobbying
Consultation with private actors happens at various stages of EU trade policy-
making. Business interests, furthermore, affect the use of instruments of commercial
defence, with which the Community tries to ensure equal competition for European
and foreign firms. During trade negotiations and with respect to instruments of
commercial defence, the solicitation by the Commission plays a key role in shaping
the access of private actors to the policy-making process.
2
The EU complaint concerned the Helms-Burton Act, a US law sanctioning European
foreign investors in Cuba.
9
1.2.1. Trade policy consultation with private actors
Even though discussions between the Commission and the Article 133
Committee on negotiation objectives are not public, the Commission consults
extensively with firms, interest groups and NGOs in order to define specific stakes in
its proposal. The EU consultation procedure is less formal than the system of Trade
Advisory Committees in the U.S., but the Commission DG Trade and DG Industry
maintain stable relations with groups such as the Union of Industries of the European
Community (UNICE) or sectoral business associations. In 1998, the Commission tried
to formalize its consultation and include a broader range of interest groups by
instituting a Civil Society Dialogue on the upcoming round of negotiations (Van den
Hoven 2002; De Bièvre and Dür 2007). Both business interests and public interest
groups now participate in the Civil Society Dialogue. However, unlike the U.S.
advisory system, the Commission is under no legal obligation to consult with the Civil
Society Dialogue or to take its reports into consideration.
Yet input from interest groups is valuable to the European Commission
because it can help strengthen its negotiation stances vis-à-vis the member states and
its trading partners. During the Uruguay Round, American negotiators cooperated
closely with U.S. industry representatives. By contrast, the European business
community was largely absent from the negotiations, despite the importance of
multilateral trading stakes. Only UNICE declared in favour of the Commission
position, and Jacques Delors complained openly about the lack of business support
(Grant 1994: 83-5; Van den Hoven 2002: 10).
Integrating business interests into the formulation of trade objectives therefore
became an important goal for the European Commission in the 1990s. One of the
10
most noted initiatives was the Transatlantic Business Dialogue (TABD), founded by
the U.S. Secretary of Commerce Ron Brown and European Trade Commissioner Sir
Leon Brittan in 1995. The aim of the TABD was to bring together CEOs of American
and European companies so that they could “pre-negotiate” issues relevant to
transatlantic trade (Coen and Grant 2000; Cowles 2001). Similarly, the Commission
encouraged the creation of other consultative associations, such as the European
Service Forum, launched in January 1999. Initiatives such as the Civil Society
Dialogue, the TABD or the European Service Forum illustrate the extent to which the
Commission solicits participation from private actors and is willing to listen to their
suggestions.
However, individual groups have few means of putting direct pressure on the
Commission to ensure that their demands will be taken into account. Within each
member state, they can try to lobby their governments to affect the consensus between
member states and the Commission during all phases of the policy cycle. They can
also contact the European Parliament, which holds hearings and produces reports on
trade issues, but this will do little more than shape the atmosphere in which EU
objectives are determined and monitored (Woolcock 2000: 380). During the adoption
phase, national parliaments and the European Parliament may play a greater role in
the future, especially now that co-decision has been extended by the Treaty of
Amsterdam, but lobbying on trade policy still concentrates on the interchange
between the Commission and member governments.
1.2.2. Instruments of commercial defence
In addition to ongoing trade negotiations, business lobbying can also target
separate administrative procedures to ensure protection against ‘unfair’ foreign
11
competition. These instruments of commercial defence include anti-dumping and
countervailing duties and the Trade Barriers Regulation of 1994. All of these
administrative instruments require the identification of unfair competition practices,
for which firms often have better information than governments. Over time, the EU
has therefore tried to facilitate business input, so as to identify the greatest possible
number of trade barriers or obstacles to competition.
Anti-dumping measures, by far the most commonly used instrument of
commercial defence, seek to punish exporters who sell their goods in the EU below
the cost of their domestic production. The procedure begins with a complaint filed by
industry representatives, which the Commission then decides to pursue or not. In the
event of an investigation, the Commission studies in consultation with the national
authorities whether there is evidence of dumping or injury to a European industry and
seeks proof that the imposition of duties would be in the ‘Community interest’.
Hearings are held to define the Community interest and to make it difficult for narrow
protectionist interests to pursue anti-dumping actions (Woolcock 2000: 389-90). In
fact, petitioners need to represent 50% of the injured industry, which makes it hard for
individual firms to file a complaint (De Bièvre 2002: 86). After the imposition of a
provisional duty by the Commission, the Council can decide by simple majority to
reject the duty or to impose definite action.
Until the beginning of the World Trade Organization (WTO), which replaced
GATT in 1995, the commercial policy of the EU was relatively defensive. European
trade officials had simultaneously to respond to demands for protection through anti-
dumping measures and to face the U.S., which actively sought to dismantle European
trade barriers. Faced with “aggressive unilateralism” from the U.S. (Bhagwati and
12
Patrick 1991), the EU had sought to create a New Commercial Policy Instrument in
1984, which tried to emulate U.S. business–government cooperation in identifying
trade barriers. Unlike the U.S. model, the European procedure was marred with
difficulties. In its ten year history, European firms filed only seven petitions (Shaffer
2003: 84-94). In December 1994, the instrument was replaced by the Trade Barriers
Regulation, which supporters were hoping would have more teeth. Innovations
included the right of individual firms to petition the Commission directly, as may
member governments. Furthermore, the petitioner no longer needs to provide proof of
injury in order to file the complaint. The Trade Barrier Regulation requires the EU to
exhaust all available multilateral dispute settlement procedures before resorting to
unilateral action, which means that the procedure serves mostly as a means of
identifying potential WTO dispute settlement cases.
Indeed, soliciting industry help in identifying such cases was one of the main
motivations behind the Trade Barrier Regulation. Traditional international trade
disputes were initiated by the Commission in consultation with the Article 133
Committee. Lacking close cooperation with business interests and trade associations,
the EU was much less able to exploit the WTO Dispute Settlement Body when it was
first established in 1995. The U.S., by contrast, brought several high-profile cases
against the EU, and filed 8 of the first 15 complaints resulting in panels.
3
Commission
3
The EU, in turn, brought only two, both jointly with the US, against third countries
Gregory C. Shaffer (2003), Defending Interests: Public-Private Partnerships in WTO
Litigation. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press..
13
officials felt that they needed to show more initiative and started to work actively to
gain industry support and industry’s technical expertise on existing trade barriers.
In February 1996, the Commission launched a new Market Access Strategy,
tactically announced by Sir Leon Brittan as “D-Day for European Trade Policy” to an
audience of major exporting companies (Shaffer 2003: 68). Within DG Trade, a
Market Access Unit was established, the primary role of which was to interact with
business actors to gather information on existing trade barriers. A central pillar of the
work was the maintenance of a Market Access Database (see De Bièvre 2002: 96-
100).
4
By centralizing information on trade barriers and involving firms in the
collection of information, the EU was hoping to be able to counter the aggressive
private–public partnerships of U.S. trade policy. As the administration of instruments
of commercial defence shows, the Commission explicitly urged business participation
in instruments of commercial defence in order to gain leverage over its trading
partners.
1.3. Trade-offs in multi-level trade lobbying
The study of trade negotiations and of the administration of instruments of
commercial defence illustrates how important business participation is for the internal
and external negotiations of the European Commission. The solicitation is based on
the Commission’s hopes of increasing its technical expertise, its legitimacy, its ability
to maintain consensus among the member states and its leverage in trade negotiations.
However, since Commission officials do not depend on re-election by constituency
4
Available from within the EU at
http://mkaccdb.eu.int.
14
interests, firms cannot exert direct pressure on European officials to reinforce their
demands. Therefore, business access is not automatic; it depends on the degree to
which private actors can offer the elements the Commission is interested in. Business
lobbying on trade is thus marked by a particular exchange logic, where firms provide
expertise and support in order to gain access to the policy process (Bouwen 2002;
Mahoney 2004).
The selective access at the European level creates a two-channel logic for
business lobbyists, which specifies different routes according to the content that firms
seek to defend. Classical protectionism is easier to achieve in interaction with national
governments, while cooperation on the elaboration of pan-European solutions
promises an excellent working relationship with the European Commission. Pan-
European trade policy lobbying can be in support of liberalization, but it can also
consist of regulatory protectionism that does not discriminate on the grounds of
nationality but appeals instead to a greater Community interest.
In fact, the tendency of the EU to defend a rather liberal external trade policy
is relatively recent. Hanson (1998) argues that member states maintained national
levels of protection in sensitive sectors throughout the 1970s and 1980s, despite the
fact that a common commercial policy was enshrined in the Treaty of Rome.
However, through the completion of the internal market, member states lost their
ability to use national policy tools, in particular due to the legislative instruments
available to the Commission in enforcing market integration (Schmidt 2000).
Moreover, EU voting rules make it difficult to replace national policies with
protectionism at the EU level (Hanson 1998: 56). Consensual decision-making on
15
trade policy means that measures favouring the sensitive industries in only a few
countries will be vetoed by other countries.
Yet, even if the Commission is more liberal than many of the member states,
supranational trade policy initiatives are not always aimed at reducing trade barriers.
In fact, the Commission does not have an a priori tendency to liberalize; it merely
seeks to develop pan-European policy solutions that do not create cleavages between
member states in order to avoid deadlock. Liberalization happens to be a pan-
European solution, but pan-European regulation is also possible. Many have noted
that the liberalization objectives of the EU often appear like an exercise in
international regulation rather than the complete abandonment of all trade barriers
(Winters 2001; Cremona 2001). Alasdair Young (2002) argues that EU external
policy is most accurately described as an attempt to extend European cooperation to
third countries. Moreover, regulatory harmonization within the single market
infrequently creates “regulatory peaks”, as many of the prominent trade disputes
between the EU and third countries illustrate (Young 2004). In other words, even
though we should expect protectionist lobbying to employ national routes and
businesses supporting liberalization to develop partnerships with the European
Commission, we might also find lobbyists defending new kinds of regulatory
protectionism that applies equally across member states.
5
5
Regulatory protectionism can be especially successful if elaborated in cooperation with directorate-
generals specialized in a particular sector of economic activity. While DG Trade might push for trade
liberalization, DG Agriculture, DG Industry, DG Transport and Energy or DG Information Society will
be more likely to elaborate sector specific regulatory arrangements that enshrine advantages for
European industries in world markets. I thank Manfred Elsig for raising this point.
16
2. Lobbying for protectionism or liberalization
What does this mean for industry lobbyists and why is it relevant to
distinguish between classic protectionism and pan-European regulatory
protectionism? With few exceptions, European trade policy applies to all industries
alike, so we should expect producers and firms to move their lobbying efforts to the
supranational level. Surprisingly, this is not the case. By comparing lobbying in
agriculture and textiles and clothing, we can see that protectionist lobbying is only
successful when it is supported within the member states, which is why lobbyists
eventually have to concentrate their efforts on the domestic route. Tellingly, lobbyists
targeting the Commission to maintain import restrictions on textiles and clothing were
ignored in the absence of member state pressure. By contrast, a study of the service
trade shows how business lobbyists have been able to influence the European
Commission’s objective once they embraced liberalization as a policy objective. This
was easy for the exporting companies in financial services, but required an important
redefinition of policy demands in telecommunication services, where firms were not
naturally inclined to support liberalization. Distinguishing between the types of
demands can thus help to explain the success or failure of trade policy lobbying in the
EU.
2.1. Resistance to foreign competition: agriculture and textiles
2.1.1. Agriculture
The agricultural market, one of the most integrated markets in the European
Union, is characterized by a highly centralized structure of interest representation at
17
the supranational level: the Comité des organizations professionnelles agricoles
(COPA), founded in 1958. Despite the close, traditionally quasi-corporatist relations
between COPA and the EU Institution on the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP),
lobbying on multilateral trade issues has, most importantly, passed through national
channels. Starting in the 1980s, the crisis of CAP dissolved the consensus between
national agricultural organizations and left space for a more pluralist organization of
agricultural interest groups. Several unified demonstration in Brussels
notwithstanding, the diversification of interest representation implies that interest
representation on external trade is mediated by the member states (Delorme 2002).
Indeed, during the first years of the Uruguay Round, national farmer
organizations, most notably in France and Germany, lobbied heavily to ensure that
their governments did not cede ground on agricultural liberalization. In December
1990, strong internal divisions between the EU member states led to a rejection of the
settlement on agriculture that was supposed to conclude the Uruguay Round. The
Commission hoped to strike a compromise by tying the multilateral negotiations to a
reform of CAP. At the beginning of the CAP reform process, the Commission had
tried to consult with national farmers’ unions, but eventually abandoned its contacts
when it realized that farmers were not willing to move away from the status quo (Vahl
1997: 149). As a consequence, the Commission negotiated directly with the member
states and isolated itself from the critical farmers’ union. In reaction, “farmers’ unions
simply intensified their lobbying activities at the member state level” to block CAP
reform and concession in the GATT negotiations (Van den Hoven 2002: 11). Once
the Commission succeeded in negotiating a compromise with the U.S. at Blair House
in Washington, D.C. in 1992, it was again the French government which threatened to
18
veto the agreement. Since Germany had shifted its position to support the Blair House
Accord, France ended up in an isolated position and did not carry through its threat
(Balaam 1999: 60).
During the new round of trade talks, opposition to liberalization was also
channelled through national routes. France and Ireland publicly criticized the
Commission’s negotiating position during the Doha ministerial meeting, arguing that
the defence of CAP ought to be the EU’s priority for negotiations (Van den Hoven
2002: 19-20). Until the time of writing, member state disagreement has severely
constrained the Commission’s room for manoeuvre in the current negotiations. It is
thus member state opposition, not agricultural lobbying, that explains development in
agricultural trade negotiations. For the Commission, successful negotiations require
neutralizing member state opposition, not resisting protectionist lobbyists at the
supranational level.
2.1.2. Textiles and clothing
As in agriculture, protectionism in textiles and clothing was achieved through
national strategies. Inversely, when interest groups had to start interacting with the
European Commission, lobbying for protectionism became increasingly difficult.
Protectionism in textiles and clothing dates was enshrined in four successive
Multifibre Arrangements (MFA) from 1974 to 1994 and ended with a Uruguay Round
Agreement on Textiles and Clothing, which stipulated that the MFA will be phased
out over a ten-year period.
6
6
For an historical overview, see Aggarwal Vinod K. Aggarwal (1985), Liberal
Protectionism: The International Politics of Organized Textile Trade. Berkeley:
19
Throughout the MFA period, the orientation of the respective arrangements
resulted from intense intergovernmental bargaining. The relatively moderate EC
policy on MFA I (1974-6) was influenced by the liberal German and Dutch approach,
which resisted U.S. calls for strict protectionism. Since the European industry had not
yet lost its comparative advantage, the Commission did not want to intervene. Once
the textiles and clothing trade balance deteriorated, the Committee for the Textile
Industries in the European Community (COMITEXTIL) lobbied heavily in Brussels
to draw attention to the dramatic fall in employment in the sector. Unimpressed and
doubting the reliability of the figures, the Commission maintained that it would be
wrong to give in to these protectionist demands. But things were different in the
Council. Member states felt concerned about the health of their textiles and clothing
industries and announced that the Community policy should be centred on voluntary
export restraints (Ugur 1998: 660). In the difficult economic times of the late 1970s,
the UK had joined France and Ireland’s strict protectionist demands, supported also in
Italy. Moderate countries seeking a simple renewal of the MFA were eventually
outnumbered (Aggarwal 1985: 146). Faced with insistent member states determined
to protect what they considered to be their national interests, the Commission had to
switch to a protectionist trade policy during MFA II and MFA III (1977-85).
The shift toward gradual liberalization under MFA IV (1986-1994) was tied to
the desire of developed countries to open up trade in services and other new issues
University of California Press. and Hoekman and Kostecki Bernard M. Hoekman and
Michel M. Kostecki (2001), The Political Economy of the World Trading System.
Oxford: Oxford University Press..
20
(Woolcock 2000: 378). Yet protectionist lobbying at the European level had not
ceased in 1985. COMITEXTIL worked hard to draw attention to the difficult situation
in the sector. In spite of this tactic’s previous success, the industry’s difficulties were
seized on by opponents of textile protection to show that earlier measures had not left
the industry better off. As European countries turned away from Keynesian demand
management, member state support faded. Despite intense lobbying from
COMITEXTIL, trade unions and other textile associations, national representatives on
the Article 133 Committee and COREPER were able to work out a compromise in
favour of gradual liberalization. In 1989, moreover, the Commission accepted the
midterm review of the Uruguay Round, against the insistence of the textile industry
association (Ugur 1998: 663). The Commission later issued a communication
stressing that restructuring was appropriate for the industry and Sir Leon Brittan
announced to a shocked industry audience that “the textile industry is a normal
industry,” (cited in Scheffer 2003). Without the backing of the member states,
protectionist lobbying in textiles and clothing at the EU level was a failure.
In a last attempt to secure special treatment in EU trade policy, industry
representatives formed a new coalition in the early 1990s, the European Textile and
Clothing Coalition, to avert the dangers of the new policy orientation. Simultaneously,
the European Trade Union Committee for Textiles began to organize meetings and
demonstrations. All of these efforts were largely ignored by the Commission, which
insisted that the industry’s problems had to be resolved by securing market openings
in third countries (Ugur 1998: 664-5). At the conclusion of the Uruguay Round, the
EU had endorsed the WTO’s Agreement on Textiles and Clothing, which was to
phase out all protection by January 2005.
21
Faced with this new reality, the textile industry had to reorganize.
COMITEXTIL, while other textile associations founded a new European association
in 1995: the European Apparel and Textile Organization (EURATEX). Needing to
work with the Commission in order to influence or delay the integration of sensitive
categories into the WTO agreement, EURATEX launched a review of its strategy
(Scheffer 2003). In contrast to the unsuccessful pressure lobbying that had
characterized earlier protectionist demands, European industry representatives
decided to engage in a more cooperative manner with the European Institutions.
As Jacomet (2000: 307) underlines, the new “interactive lobbying” during the
WTO negotiations in the early 1990s had differed sharply from previous activities
because lobbyists had to accept a “trade-off” in the policy demands they could voice:
they exchanged the elimination of the MFA for market access in third countries. Only
by embracing a policy stance centred on market access did textile lobbyists maintain
their contacts with the European Institutions. Indeed, the selection logic of the EU
Institutions forcing European industry representatives to reframe their demands helps
to explain why the EU textile industry became supportive of foreign market access
while its American counterpart continued to press for strict protection. The need to
supply a specific kind of lobbying at the supranational level also becomes clear in the
reorganization of EURATEX. As a result of its internal review, EURATEX decided
to develop a more comprehensive policy “in order to be seen as relevant partners for
policy-makers,” (Scheffer 2003: 108). Faced with very heterogeneous demands from
its national associations, EURATEX now aims not to counteract national lobbying,
but to promote synergies between domestic and European efforts. After the lobbying
22
failures of the past, EURATEX’s approach today is to focus on pan-European stances
to maintain its leadership role at the EU level.
At the end of the Agreement on Textiles and Clothing’s transition period in
2005, European companies complained vigorously about Chinese competition. Still,
they acknowledged that the abandonment of the quota system was beyond their
control. Whether they liked it or not, “the affected companies had to accept the new
logic in order to be able to influence the calendar, the modalities of the new measures
or the transition aid,” (Jacomet 2004: 5). In the absence of member state pressure for
protection, successful business–government relations at the supranational level
required going along with the liberalization objective of the European Commission.
2.2. Developing pan-European policy solutions: trade in services
The multilateral General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) that entered
into force with the founding of the WTO in 1995 is often cited as a prime example of
business influence over trade policy. According to many observers, the American
financial service companies and its Coalition for Service Industries played a key role
in bringing the issue onto the international negotiating table (Drake and Nicolaïdis
1992; Sell 2000; Woll 2004). On the European side, firms were much less in evidence
during the service negotiations in the Uruguay Round and the sectoral negotiations
that followed GATS. However, the European Commission did consult extensively
with industry representatives in two sectors: financial services and telecommunication
services (Van den Hoven 2002: 10).
23
2.2.1. Financial services
At the conclusion of the Uruguay Round, countries agreed to continue sectoral
negotiations on financial services to obtain more detailed liberalization commitments.
By the initial deadline in 1995, the U.S. declared itself unsatisfied with the existing
offers and walked out of the negotiations. Behind the position of the U.S. government
was the frustration of the U.S. private sector, which had helped to put services on the
WTO agenda and now felt that it was not achieving sufficient market access in
foreign countries (Woolcock 1998).
Faced with the U.S. refusal, the EU assumed the leadership in the financial
service talks and encouraged WTO members to negotiate an interim agreement
without the U.S. in 1995 and to extend the talks until December 1997. Over the next
two years, the European Commission went out of its way to gain the support of
European financial service firms so it could counter the influence of the U.S. private
sector. Indeed, representatives of “Citicorp, Goldman Sachs, Merrill Lynch and the
insurance companies – particularly the American Insurance Group and Aetna –
established command posts” near the WTO headquarters and conferred with
American negotiators throughout the financial service talks (Andrews 1997).
Business lobbying comparable to the activities of the U.S. Coalition of Service
Industries was only common in the United Kingdom, where financial service firms
had founded British Invisibles in 1986, an association to promote the interests of its
members, which later turned into International Financial Services London. Part of
British Invisibles was the working committee LOTIS (the acronym for Liberalisation
Of Trade In Services), which dates back to the early 1980s (see Wesselius 2001). For
the European Commission, working with these private sector associations was crucial,
24
because they felt that European firms could best engage the U.S. private sector in a
continued dialogue. Transnational business negotiations began at the World Economic
Forum in Davos, Switzerland in 1996. U.S., UK and European financial service
representatives met in the office of British Invisibles and eventually formed the
Financial Leaders Group to promote the interests of the affected firms on both sides of
the Atlantic (Sell 2000: 178).
The European Trade Commissioner, Sir Leon Brittan, welcomed the creation
of this group and worked closely with its European chair, Andrew Buxton of Barclays
Bank (Wesselius 2002: 7). For the EU negotiators, the Financial Leaders Group was
an important channel through which they hoped to moderate U.S. expectations, in
particular by addressing the concerns of the U.S. private sectors, which had previously
brought the talks to a standstill (Woolcock 1998: 33). Sir Leon Brittan had long been
frustrated with the lack of support among European companies and tried to encourage
them to mobilize around the issue of international trade liberalization. A
representative of the European service sector remembers: “At one occasion, he finally
invited a series of CEOs for dinner and said something to the effect of ‘either you will
get organized, or I will take the decisions single-handedly’.”
7
In contrast to the aggressive lobbying of U.S. financial service firms, European
firms entered negotiations not so much on their own initiative but, most importantly,
in response to the active encouragement of the European Commission, which was
looking for business support for the difficult financial service talks in the 1990s. The
close business–government relationship that developed in the EU after 1996 was
7
Interview with the author in Brussels, November 13, 2002.
25
based on the shared aim of liberalizing the sector. After an unexpected change in the
position of the Asian countries during the currency crisis in 1997, negotiators finally
reached an agreement on December 12, 1997. Yet the cooperation between financial
service firm leaders and the European Commission went even further than the
Financial Service Agreement. In 1998, Sir Leon Brittan asked Andrew Buxton once
again to create a select group of, this time, purely European business leaders. The
European Service Forum, launched on January 26, 1999, today ensures the
Commission’s continued support for the liberalization of service industries and
consequentially benefits from privileged access to trade policy-making at the
supranational level. Had European firms not supported liberalization, it is highly
unlikely that they would have been able to work so closely with EU policy-makers.
2.2.2. Telecommunications
In telecommunications, the position of firms was more difficult. European
network operators had long benefited from privileged positions as monopoly
providers in their home countries. The WTO’s sectoral negotiations on basic
telecommunications liberalization from 1994-1997 coincided with the liberalization of
the internal EU market. While firms wanted to benefit from foreign market access
once telecommunication markets were liberalized, they were also concerned about
protecting their home market positions. Solicited by the European Commission,
European operators therefore adopted a pro-liberalization stance in the mid-1990s,
which allowed them to follow and influence the content of the multilateral negotiation
in the WTO while still maintaining close ties to their home governments in order to
defend national interests on specific issues.
26
In fact, the project of European telecommunications liberalization had met
with very different echoes in European member states. The United Kingdom and the
Nordic countries had introduced competition in their home markets and pushed
actively for Europe-wide liberalization. Germany, France and the Benelux countries
had initiated more moderate reforms, but had their reservations about complete
liberalization. However, the Southern countries – Italy, Greece, Spain and Portugal –
were not interested in changing their telecommunication systems (see Noam 1992).
The struggle between the European Commission and the member states over internal
telecommunications liberalization began in 1987 and is recounted elsewhere in great
detail (e.g. Sandholtz 1998; Thatcher 1999b; Eliassen and Sjøvaag 1999; Holmes and
Young 2002). After some judicial wrangling over EU competences, the Commission
was able to propose the liberalization of telephone services in 1993 and infrastructures
in 1994. In 1996, member states reached agreement on implementing liberalization by
January 1, 1998. What is important for an understanding of the WTO involvement of
European network operators is the consultation efforts made by the European
Commission during the internal liberalization project.
Trying to gain support in the face of member state resistance, Martin
Bangemann, European Commissioner for Industry, Information Technology and
Telecommunications, called together a group of “wise men”, leaders from the telecom
industry and user companies, in order to prepare a communication on the international
competitiveness of European telecommunications. The consultation procedure is
noteworthy, because the Commission dealt with the senior officials of the national
operators directly and encouraged them to evaluate their position in the
internationalizing market. Under pressure from user companies and competition from
27
liberalized countries attracting telecommunications-based firms, operators in France
and Germany began to concentrate on reform and internationalization, and therefore
supported the EU liberalization (Thatcher 1999a). With the backing of the leading
European telecommunications providers, the report issued by the senior official
group, the so-called Bangemann report, was important for encouraging member states
onto the route of liberalization (High-Level Group on the Information Society 1994).
Lobbying on multilateral liberalization was closely connected to internal
liberalization. Before 1996, European network operators were not involved in the
sectoral negotiations that had begun in 1994 (Woll 2004). With the announcement of
the 1998 deadline, the European Telecommunication Network Operators association
(ETNO), founded in 1992, was able to gather support for multilateral liberalization as
well. A member of the WTO working group recalls: “We had good relations with the
European Commission. There was no opposition: the Commission works for Europe
and we work for Europe as well.”
8
ETNO fully supported the multilateral negotiations
and helped the Commission negotiate the Basic Telecom Agreement in 1997.
Indeed, most operators affirm having been in support of the 1997 agreement
and having engaged actively through their European association throughout the talks.
Despite these declarations, many operators had concerns about losing their national
privileges and so used their national ties to maintain a degree of control over access to
their home markets. Telefónica, the Spanish operator, for example, insisted on
restricting non-EC investment to the Spanish market, despite the fact that it had
become an important overseas investor in Latin America. When the U.S. criticized the
8
Interview with the author in Brussels, September 3, 2003.
28
Spanish position, negotiations over the case turned into bilateral talks between the
Commission and the Spanish government, which had taken up the highly politicized
issue (Niemann 2004: 399). Similarly, network operators in other countries tried to
guarantee national privileges through the implementation of the EC regulatory
framework. Member states and their regulatory agencies enjoyed immense freedom to
determine interconnection terms and tariffs between networks or to impose universal
service conditions. In contrast to British Telecom, which received no extra funding for
universal service, France Télécom had the right to obtain compensation (Thatcher
1999a). At the same time that ETNO was lobbying for reciprocal liberalization of
basic telecommunication services through the WTO, national operators were seeking
to maintain regulatory advantages, i.e. restrictions to foreign market access, through
their national governments.
3. Conclusion
The comparison between agriculture, textiles and clothing, financial services
and telecommunication services shows that trade policy lobbying in the EU is marked
by a two-channel logic. Protectionism (agriculture) is best defended through the
national route, while lobbying in support of liberalization (financial services) happens
at the supranational level, in particular through contacts with the European
Commission. Companies that seek both foreign market access and restrictions to
competition in their home markets therefore tend to adopt an ambiguous position:
they choose to support liberalization “in general” in order to stay in contact with the
European Commission, but also work through their member states to maintain
national restrictions (telecommunications). Without the backing of their home
29
governments, protectionist lobbying that impedes European market integration is
unsuccessful at the supranational level (textiles and clothing). In trade policy, firms
thus face a trade-off. If they want to maintain good relations with the European
Commission, they have to frame their demands in terms of pan-European solutions,
which often means moving away from their immediate interest.
The entrepreneurial role of the European Commission in creating public–
private contacts on trade policy has several implications. First of all, not just
businesses but also other interest groups, such as environmental or social NGOs, can
be solicited for input into the European trade policy process. As current consultation
demonstrates, the Commission has indeed made an effort to include an ever broader
range of actors in order to increase its legitimacy and work towards a policy
consensus (Woolcock 2000). The increasing importance of NGO consultation on trade
issues means that firms are now obliged to work on their public image. One business
representative of a petroleum company even estimated that 80% of his public affairs
responsibilities concern contacts with NGOs, not governments.
9
However, firms
remain the principal source of expertise on trade barriers and will therefore come into
their own whenever the EU seeks to increase its leverage vis-à-vis trading partners
such as the U.S.. While NGOs may affect the atmosphere of trade negotiations, it is
important not to overestimate the direct influence of public interest groups, even
though the Commission tries to take their opinion into account through the Civil
Society Dialogue (De Bièvre and Dür 2007).
9
Cited by Dominique Jacoment, board member of EURATEX, at a book conference on “Interest
groups and the State in France,” CEVIPOF – Sciences Po, Paris, on January 11, 2007.
30
Second, the complexity of the strategic interactions in European trade policy
caution against superficial analyses of trade policy demands in the EU. Because of the
two-channel logic, we should expect to find many firms declaring themselves in
favour of trade liberalization, simply because this ensures them greater access to the
EU trade negotiators. A study of trade preferences thus needs to distinguish between
the strategic positions of firms and their underlying preferences, which might be much
more ambiguous than the official declarations would lead us to believe.
Finally, the comparison between the various business–government relations
shows that European trade policy lobbying is complex. To assume that trade policy
simply reflects producer demands, as many have suggested in the case of the U.S.,
would be to miss important aspects of public–private relations in the EU. While firms
might capture their government’s positions or even the supranational agenda in certain
cases, the Commission also instrumentalizes European firms and even affects the
content of their lobbying demands. This runs counter to the common assumption that
industry demands and governments simply execute trade policy. Such a demand-side
conception of policy-making runs through classic trade theory, international political
economy and the economic analysis of business-government interactions. This article
has tried to demonstrate that it is inappropriate for an understanding of European trade
policy. The EU’s common commercial policy results as much from producer
demands as it does from the complex decision-making procedures, the institutional
self-interest of public actors and the power struggles created by their interaction.
Considering the EU institutions as the passive supplier of trade regulation obscures
some of the most crucial mechanisms of this policy process.
31
Acknowledgements
I would like to thank Manfred Elsig, Holger Döring and Armin Schäfer and the
editors for their helpful remarks.
References
Aggarwal, V. K. (1985) Liberal Protectionism: The International Politics of
Organized Textile Trade. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Andrews, E. L. (1997) 'Agreement to Open up World Financial Markets is Reached',
New York Times, December 13.
Balaam, D. N. (1999) 'Agricultural Trade Policy', in B. Hocking and S. McGuire
(eds.), Trade Politics: International, Domestic and Regional Perspectives,
London: Routledge, 52-66.
Bhagwati, J. and Patrick, H. T. (eds.) (1991) Aggressive Unilateralism: America's 301
Trade Policy and the World Trading System, New York: Harvester
Wheatsheaf.
Bouwen, P. (2002) 'Corporate Lobbying in the European Union: The Logic of
Access', Journal of European Public Policy 9(3): 365-390.
Broscheid, A. and Coen, D. (2003) 'Insider and Outsider Lobbying in the European
Commission', European Union Politics 4(2): 165-189.
Coen, D. (1999) 'The impact of U.S. lobbying practice on the European business-
government relationships', California Management Review 41(4): 27-44.
Coen, D. and Grant, W. (2000) 'Corporate Political Strategy and Global Policy: A
Case Study of the Transaltantic Business Dialogue', Regulation Initiative
Working Paper(42).
32
Cowles, M. G. (2001) 'The Transatlantic Business Dialogue and Domestic Business-
Government Relations', in J. Caporaso, M. G. Cowles and T. Risse (eds.),
Transforming Europe : Europeanization and Domestic Change, Ithaca, N.Y.:
Cornell University Press, 159-179.
Cremona, M. (2001) 'Neutrality or Discrimination? The WTO, the EU and External
Trade', in G. De Búrca and J. Scott (eds.), The EU and the WTO: Legal and
Constitutional Issues, Oxford: Hart Publishing, 151-184.
De Bièvre, D. (2002) 'The WTO and Domestic Coalitions: The Effects of
Negotiations and Enforcement in the European Union', Ph.D. Disseration,
Department of Political and Social Sciences, San Domenico di Fiesole:
European University Institute.
De Bièvre, D. and Dür, A. (2005) 'Constituency Interests and Delegation in European
and American Trade Policy', Comparative Political Studies 38(10): 1271-
1296.
De Bièvre, D. and Dür, A. (2007) 'Inclusion without Influence? Civil Society
Involvement in European Trade Policy', Journal of Public Policy 27(1): 79-
101
Delorme, H. (2002) 'Les agriculteurs et les institutions communautaires: du
corporatisme agricole au lobbyisme agro-alimentaire', in R. Balme, D.
Chabanet and V. Wright (eds.), L'action collective en Europe, Paris: Presses de
Sciences Po, 313-346.
Drake, W. J. and Nicolaïdis, K. (1992) 'Ideas, Interests, and Institutionalization: Trade
in Services and the Uruguay Round', International Organization 46(1): 37-
100.
33
Eliassen, K. A. and Sjøvaag, M. (eds.) (1999) European Telecommunication
Liberalisation, London: Routledge.
Elsig, M. (2002) The EU's Common Commercial Policy: Institutions, Interests and
Ideas. Aldershot: Ashgate.
Elsig, M. (2007) 'Delegation and Agency in EU Trade Policy Making: Bringing
Brussels Back In', Paper presented at the EUSA Conference, Montreal, 17-18
May.
Frieden, J. and Martin, L. L. (2002) 'International Political Economy: Global and
Domestic Interactions', in I. Katznelson and H. Milner (eds.), Political
Science: The State of the Discipline, New York: W.W. Norton & Company,
118-146.
Grande, E. (1996) 'The State and Interest Groups in a Framework of Multi-Level
Decision-Making: The Case of the European Union', Journal of European
Public Policy 3(3): 318-338.
Grant, C. (1994) Delors: Inside the House that Jacques Built. London: Nicholas
Brealey Publishing.
Hanson, B. (1998) 'What Happened to Fortress Europe? External Trade Policy
Liberalization in the European Union', International Organization 52(1): 55-
86.
High-Level Group on the Information Society (1994) Recommendations to the
European Council: Europe and the Global Information Society. May 26.
Brussels: European Commission.
<
http://europa.eu.int/ISPO/infosoc/backg/bangeman.html
>
34
Hoekman, B. M. and Kostecki, M. M. (2001) The Political Economy of the World
Trading System. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Holmes, P. and Young, A. (2002) 'Liberalizing and Reregulating Telecommunications
in Europe: A Common Framework and Persistent Differences', in P. Guerrieri
and H.-E. Scharrer (eds.), Trade, Investment and Competition Policies in the
Global Economy: The Case of the International Telecommunications Regime,
Baden-Baden: Nomos, 119-158.
Jacomet, D. (2000) 'Les stratégies d'entreprises face aux politiques publiques: le
lobbying des producteurs occidentaux et la politique commerciale
internationale dans le textile-habillement', Ph.D. Thesis, Gestion, Paris:
Université Paris IX - Dauphine.
Jacomet, D. (2004) 'Les changements induits par l'intégration européenne et la
mondialisation sur la stratégie d'influence des entreprises: le cas de l'Union des
Industries Textiles (UIT)', Paper presented at the conference "Interest groups
in the 21st century in France and Europe," Sciences Po Paris, 24-25
September.
Johnson, M. (1998) European Community Trade Policy and the Article 113
Committee. London: Royal Institute of International Affairs.
Mahoney, C. (2004) 'The Power of Institutions: State and Interest Group Activity in
the European Union', European Union Politics 5(4): 441-466.
Meunier, S. (2000a) 'EU Trade Policy: The ‚Exclusive' versus Shared Competence
Debate', in M. G. Cowles and M. Smith (eds.), The State of the European
Union: Risks, Reform, Resistance, and Revival, Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 325-346.
35
Meunier, S. (2000b) 'What Single Voice? European Institutions and EU-U.S. Trade
Negotiations', International Organizations 54(1): 103-136.
Meunier, S. (2005) Trading Voices: The European Union in International
Commercial Negotiations. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Meunier, S. and Nicolaïdis, K. (1999) 'Who Speaks for Europe? The Delegation of
Trade Authority in the European Union', Journal of Common Market Studies
37(3): 477-501.
Niemann, A. (2004) 'Between Communicative Action and Strategic Action: the
Article 113 Committee and the Negotiations on the WTO Basic
Telecommunications Agreement', Journal of European Public Policy 11(3):
379-407.
Noam, E. (1992) Telecommunications in Europe. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Sandholtz, W. (1998) 'The Emergence of a Supranational Telecommunications
Regime', in W. Sandholtz and A. Stone Sweet (eds.), European Integration
and Supranational Governance, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Scheffer, M. (2003) 'Textiles', in J. Greenwood (ed.), The Challenge of Change in EU
Business Associations, New York: Palgrave, 103-114.
Schmidt, S. K. (2000) 'Only an Agenda Setter? The European Commission's Power
over the Council of Ministers', European Union Politics 1(1): 37-61.
Sell, S. K. (2000) 'Big Business and the New Trade Agreements: The Future of the
WTO', in R. Stubbs and G. R. D. Underhill (eds.), Political Economy and the
Changing Global Order, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
36
Shaffer, G. C. (2003) Defending Interests: Public-Private Partnerships in WTO
Litigation. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.
Thatcher, M. (1999a) 'The Europeanisation of Regulation: The Case of
Telecommunication', EUI Working Papers 99(22).
Thatcher, M. (1999b) The Politics of Telecommunications: National Institutions,
Convergence, and Change in Britain and France. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Ugur, M. (1998) 'Explaining Protectionism and Liberalization in European Union
Trade Policy: The Case of Textiles and Clothing', Journal of European Public
Policy 5(4): 652-70.
Vahl, R. (1997) Leadership in Disguise: The Role of the European Commission in EC
Decision-Making on Agriculture in the Uruguay Round. Hants, UK: Ashgate.
Van den Hoven, A. (2002) 'Interest Group Influence on Trade Policy in a Multilevel
Polity: Analysing the EU Position at the Doha WTO Ministerial Conference',
EUI Working Papers 2002(67).
Wesselius, E. (2001) Liberalisation of Trade in Services: Corporate Power at Work,
GATSwatch Background Paper. <
www.gatswatch.org/LOTIS/LOTIS.html
>
Wesselius, E. (2002) 'Behind GATS 2000: Corporate Power at Work', Transnational
Institute Briefing Series 2002(6). <www.tni.org/reports/wto/wto4.pdf>
Winters, L. A. (2001) 'European Union Trade Policy: Actually or Just Nominally
Liberal?' in H. Wallace (ed.), Interlocking Dimensions of European
Integration, New York: Palgrave, 25-44.
Woll, C. (2004) 'The Politics of Trade Preferences: Business Lobbying on Service
Trade in the United States and the European Union', Ph.D. Dissertation,
37
Political Science, Paris / Cologne: Institut d'Etudes Politiques de Paris /
Universität zu Köln.
Woll, C. (2006) 'Lobbying in the European Union: From Sui Generis to a
Comparative Perspective', Journal of European Public Policy 13(3): 456-469.
Woolcock, S. (1998) Liberalisation of Financial Services. Unpublished manuscript
available at <
www.lse.ac.uk/collections/internationalTradePolicyUnit/
pdf/liberalisationOfFinancialServices.pdf>.
Woolcock, S. (2000) 'European Trade Policy: Global Pressures and Domestic
Constraints', in H. Wallace and W. Wallace (eds.), Policy-making in the
European Union, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 373-399.
Young, A. (2002) Extending European Cooperation: The European Union and the
"New" International Trade Agenda. Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Young, A. (2004) 'The Incidental Fortress: The Single European Market and World
Trade', Journal of Common Market Studies 42(2): 393-414.